Investigating The Link Between Inflation And Unemployment: A Study Of The Phillips Curve

The Phillips Curve and its Historical Significance

The Phillips curve illustrates the link involving the inflation rate and the level of unemployment. Despite having forerunners, A. W. H. Phillips’ research of wage unemployment and inflation in the United Kingdom from 1861 to 1957 represents a seismic shift in the evolution of macroeconomic policy (Chowdhury, & Sarkar, 2017) Phillips discovered a constant indirect relationships: when unemployment is high, earnings grew slowly; when unemployment is low, earnings grew quickly.

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

Phillips hypothesized that the lesser the rate of unemployment, the tighter the labour supply and, as a result, the faster employers would have to boost pay to capture scarce labour. The strain eased when rate of unemployment rose. Phillips’ “curve” showed the mean link involving unemployment and income behaviour throughout the context of a business cycle (Davig, 2016). It depicted the rate of compensation inflation that would occur if a certain level of unemployment remained for a period of time.

This association was thought to be everlasting, and policymakers were faced with a decision involving great unemployment and low inflation, or low unemployment and high inflation. Nevertheless, Friedman and Phelps disputed this since they saw the source of the inverse relation as a prejudice in employees’ inflationary expectations. As a result, the inverse link involving unemployment and inflation was discovered only up to a correction of inflationary expectations, after which it returns to the level of unemployment. According to this logic, the earliest version of the Phillips curve featured a natural rate of unemployment and also inflationary expectations. As a result of this paradigm, inflation has a short-run influence on unemployment. Following a correction to the level of unemployment, there would only be a rise in inflation (Gagnon, & Collins, 2019). As a result, there are no benefits to boosting inflation to a greater level, and it should instead be low and stable.

 

How the Phillips curve’s sequence of reasoning was seen as a type of achieved significant development. Nevertheless, this altered during the 1970s with the incidence of the two oil price changes, leading to a shift in salary setters’ expectations formation. Historically, inflation fluctuated around a basic level of inflation, but in the 1970s, inflation grew continually. The likelihood that a greater inflation rate would follow a significant impact on the economy in the next year increased, nullifying the earlier trade-off involving unemployment and inflation. In the years thereafter, a substantial number of nations have seen concurrent increases in unemployment and inflation, and so this economic stagnation has resulted in a new version of the Phillips curve with forwards-looking inflation.

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

The Link between Unemployment and Income Behavior

The goal of this research is to investigate the link involving inflation and unemployment in current context. This raises the following considerations. Furthermore, can there be a negative link between unemployment and inflation in the near run? Secondly, is there a persistent trade-off involving inflation and unemployment in the country? Lastly, if a trade-off can be identified, is it a stable connection or does it fluctuate in response to variations in the macroeconomic framework? This paper is arranged as follows in order to conduct this research. The development of the Phillips curve is discussed first, followed by a deeper dive into the significance of the level of unemployment and various ways to explaining the Phillips curve in the situation of chronic low inflation. Following that is an empirical analysis of the Phillips curve for country, with a summary of the data set and an explanation to the ideas of stationary, cointegration, and vectors data transfer models. This is followed by a discussion of the estimation findings and a final assessment of the outcomes in terms of their political consequences.

The majority of current empirical research on the Phillips curve have concentrated on the investigation of market defects and the creation of predictions, especially in the context of incomplete information. As a result, we consider the following work’s outcomes. A range of data sources in the forms of cross-sectional information, time series, and panel data were employed for the study of the link between unemployment and inflation. Additionally, the estimation techniques were changed by using OLS, GLS, or GMM estimations as compared to dynamical OLS or error – correcting projections, with various outcomes (Leduc, & Wilson, 2017). For instance, a panellist estimate discovered a Phillips curve for the vast majority of OECD nations, but another study using the cointegration method only discovered a Phillips curve.

Most recent research agrees that reasonable expectations only account for a minor part of the puzzle. One method to demonstrate this is to use the combination Phillips curve, that merges the concepts of forward and backward looking forecasts, which, coupled with the seasonal element as well as a supply shock, describe the fluctuations of inflation (Blanchard, 2016). As a result, the model is still based on the concept of a natural unemployment limitation, and hence includes the assumption of numerous imperfect markets. Portion of the agent’s expectancy is formed by a hybrid of forward and backward viewing expectations, with part formed by predicted inflation expectations and part formed by a thumb rule.

The Evolution of the Phillips Curve

It was historically conventional to use actual inflation as a kind of predicted inflation as a measure of reasonable expectations (Leduc, & Wilson, 2017). To get around this risky assumption, researchers are increasingly using data on inflation projections or population inflationary forecasts. These demonstrate a clearly diminished role of forward-looking expectations and, as a result, a greater explanatory capacity for the longevity of inflationary.

Nevertheless, a frequent flaw in these models still exists. Because of the great predictive variable of past and prospective inflation, the cyclical aspect is usually insignificant and often beneficial. While forward-looking predictions seem to play a large role in generally, they cannot be deleted from the framework (Tallman, & Zaman, 2017). Forward-looking expectancies can still be used to describe the incidence of unstable economics and hyperinflation; but, this does not clarify the model’s other elements.

Aside from the broad relevance of inflationary expectations, another branch is emerging that seeks to address the unimportance and incorrect sign of the Phillips curve, as well as the potential of a variable level of unemployment. Such studies have concentrated on identifying the natural rate of unemployment that varies over time and may be altered by macroeconomic intervention. The Hodrick-Prescott filter and the Kalman filter are two commonly used approaches for predicting the forward-looking and composite Phillips curves. Another explanation for the unimportance is the idea of approaching rationality, which might result in a perpetual trade-off involving unemployment and inflation (Lipsey, 2016). This notion has been used in Sweden as well as other European nations, although there is no actual evidence to support it.

Irrespective of near-rationality notions, the hypothesis of the level of unemployment is commonly acknowledged as losing favour. Until current, the idea of frictional development can describe the rise in unemployment in Spain from the financial union’s inception. The presence of a long term trade-off involving unemployment and inflation may be demonstrated, particularly using the notion of co – integration and error – correcting frameworks (Davig, 2016). If these findings are true, it would indicate an improper data description for the use of filtration technique for identifying the natural rate of unemployment, including the Hodrick-Prescott filtration or the Kalman filtration that also justifies the lack of impact and the positive development. If this relates to the reality that, in additional to the demand and supply, the demand side will have a lasting effect on unemployment and this would reduce the benefits of the generally low rate of economic growth that has become accepted over the previous years (Chowdhury, & Sarkar, 2017). At the same time, this would simply increase the relevance of fiscal policy in the medium term and support the need for an increased inflation goal.

Literature Review

As previously stated, the two demand shocks and resulting economic stagnation altered the theoretical shape of the Phillips curve. The inclusion of the level of unemployment and forwards-looking expectations reduced the necessity of regulators’ action dramatically. Policymakers could no longer decide between great levels of inflation unemployment or low inflation and high unemployment (Gagnon, & Collins, 2019). As a result, the negative association involving unemployment and inflation was only relevant in the short run, until inflation expectations were adjusted. After expectations are adjusted, unemployment correlates to the level of unemployment at a greater level of inflation. As a result, the central bank must solely focus on fighting inflation, as a poor credibility of the reserve bank might lead to an expected rise in inflations that is not the situation. Income would rise faster than the rate of inflations, resulting in a rise in unemployment.

In the succeeding time, a current financial school emerged, aiming to identify the origins of unemployment as well as the long-run compensation processes to the level of unemployment by employing a microfoundation for economic and financial processes. In addition to inflationary pressures, they enlarged the causes for a delay in adjustment by macroeconomic constraints (Gagnon, & Collins, 2019). As a consequence, major variables such as labour rigidities and product markets such as imperfectly competitive markets, that are the outcome of rational conduct of households and enterprises, were noted. The Calvo-price establishing model is the most commonly used variation for demonstrating short and long term significance (Del Negro, et al., 2020). In the near run, it indicates certain agents’ imperfect expectations creation as well as a negative link involving unemployment and inflation. Due to macroeconomic variables restrictions, a correction in expectations will not instantly lead to a change in wages and prices as a result of the agents’ rational behaviour. Considering that inflexibility only have a short-run impact, they will ultimately lose their influence, resulting in the level of unemployment, that is a vertically Phillips curve. In regarding market mistakes that describe short-run fluctuations in unemployment, a multitude of explanations for long-run structural unemployment were discovered, most particularly the standard economic concept, which relates firms to hire workers at wages higher than the market clearing wage, resulting in a permanent rate of employment.

As a consequence of this conceptual model, the reserve bank, as originally said, is forced to focus on a low inflations objective. Nevertheless, the federal bank’s stability approach is only acceptable if the inflation objective is not missed. Moreover, fiscal policy is only allowed to have a short-term impact. A rise in governmental spending or a reduction in taxes has a short-run beneficial impact on employment, with the approximate impact controlled by two considerations: first, the fiscal policy is influenced by the amount of rigidity; and second, the federal bank’s preferences. A significant level of rigidity results in long-term beneficial fiscal policy benefits and only a modest growth in inflations (Ba?bura, & Bobeica, 2022). Considering that inflationary only begins with a lag, the financial system will raise rates late in order to reduce the impact of fiscal and monetary policy. When there is a low level of rigidity, inflation rises quickly, tempting the federal bank to raise interest rates sooner to attain the inflationary goal. Because of this interplay involving fiscal and monetary policy, the impact of fiscal policy leads in an economic slowdown, because inflation will only rise modestly after a rise in government expenditure, and the reserve bank will not increase rates. In comparison, a bank rate lowering is possible since inflation falls during a recession, and the central bank seeks to counteract this.

Empirical Analysis of the Phillips Curve

An asymmetrical impact of nominal rigidities, that strengthens and becomes more relevant in the face of chronic low inflations, is an alternatives to the level of unemployment in the long term that contributes to monetary and fiscal policy fairness. Income levels, in particularly, exhibit significantly more downwards rigidity.

These are built on a system of staggered contracts. Because new contracts are negotiated owing to information gathering, discussions, and prospective strike expenses, both sides are interested in prolonged terms. This is especially true for employees who are risk averse due to a lesser pay. As a result, they are ready to sacrifice a prospective salary gain for a while if it also means that their salaries cannot decline (Ba?bura, & Bobeica, 2022). As a result, pay reductions exceeding business benefits are only marginally achievable. Firms find it difficult to modify their pay during a specific economic slump when there is greater downwards rigidity. As a result, businesses may exit the market. In the current environment of perfectly competitive, involving market entrance obstacles, this can result in a persistent rise in unemployment. To alleviate this downwards rigidity, one approach would be to set a permanently higher inflationary objective. The present explanation for increased downward stiffness is based on two basic ideas: near rationality and resistive increase.

As per idea of close rationality, there are enduring downwards rigidities caused by certain agents’ irrational behaviour. It is primarily based on the principle of effectiveness wage, which states that workers perform more when they are paid more than the market level. A tremendously in terms of employees, a rise in the financial costs of avoiding workers, and a potential gift impact are all reasons for this. Moreover, the company has lowered expenses since turnover ratio will reduce, lowering the prices of trainees (Salisu, Ademuyiwa, & Isah, 2018). As a result, a fall in the nominal pay would result in a decrease in company productivity. While the economy will benefit from pay reductions, it would be irrational for enterprises to do so. The concept’s irrationality begins here. The notion underlying the idea of near reason is that not all workers can tell the difference between a nominal salary rise and a real wage increase. If this is true, rising inflation allows for a reduction in real wages without necessarily a reduction in nominal earnings, and has a reduced negative impact on worker performance. Moreover, enterprises’ near-rationality contributes to a widespread under-weighting of inflation. The presumption of near reason, on the other hand, is dangerous since it ignores probable income and substitution impacts of individuals and companies.

Data Set and Methodology

In addition to the abovementioned close rationality method, there is the idea of friction development, which refers to the combination involving inflation and actual frictions in the economic. This technique is predicated on the concepts of rational expectancies, the lack of money illusions, and non-permanent conceptual rigidities. One benefit of this technique over near reason is that we don’t have to figure out why people behave in irrational ways. The uneven nominal pay rigidities are explained here by labour market regulations, provided that a fall in wages is only feasible by common agreement between employers and unions, making a reduction in wage growth implausible. This gives employees a strategic edge in pay talks, which can avoid a drop in nominal earnings. The consequences will be the same as they were in the instance of close rationality. A detrimental shock can have long-run repercussions on unemployment in the case of a persistent low inflation aim. This indicates that in the context of a low and stable inflation objective, inflations have long-run consequences and there is no high level of unemployment.

This changes the significance of fiscal and monetary policy, with the consequence for macroeconomic and fiscal policy that a permanently higher inflation goal might be advantageous to offset the long-run implications of downwards wage rigidities. Furthermore, the central bank should prioritize employment above inflation. Furthermore, in the context of a permanently low inflation objective, fiscal policy must respond rapidly in the aftermath of a severe macroeconomic shock in order to avoid a permanent rise in unemployment. Because of the lack of a within and outside lag of policy operations, safety nets are especially beneficial.

 

Figure 1

The vertical curve in Figure 1 represents the long-run Phillips curve. Once unemployment is at the level specified by this curve, inflation will be stable, as per NAIRU concept. Nevertheless, policymakers will confront a macroeconomic variables trade-off in the short run, as indicated by the ‘Basic Short-Run Phillips Curve’ in the diagram. Using expansionary fiscal policy, policymakers can significantly lower the rate of unemployment, going from point A to point B. Using this short-run trade-off, nevertheless, will enhance inflationary expectations, pushing the short-run curve demand to the right to the ‘New Short-Run Phillips Curve,’ thus altering the point of balance from B to C, as per the NAIRU. As a result, any fall in unemployment under the ‘Natural Rate’ will be transitory, leading to greater inflations in the long run.

Estimation Results

Because the short-run curve extends outwards in an effort to erase unemployment, increase in the money supply exacerbates the exploitable trade-off involving unemployment and annual inflation. As a consequence, per each short-run rate of unemployment, inflation increases. The term ‘NAIRU’ comes from the fact that when actual unemployment falls below ‘NAIRU,’ inflationary increases, whereas when unemployment goes beyond it, inflation slows. Inflation is steady when the real rate is determined to it.

Correlations across the two series are presented in this section. Figure 2 depicts graphs of unemployment and inflation for the years 1980 to 2010.

 

Figure 2: Correlations between inflation and unemployment

Figure 2 shows that unemployment and inflation have had significantly distinct trend courses during the analysed time, yet variations in the two series around such two results are inversely correlated.

These two sequences do not seem to have a shared tendency, and there seems to be some (inverse) relationship involving these two factors within the time period under consideration. While unemployment has risen steadily during the time, inflation appears to have risen sharply. The negative link among unemployment and inflation is especially visible from 1980 to 1984, as well as from 1995 to 1999. This relationship is the conventional symbol for the Phillips Curve, and it is considerably distinct from zero. 

A precondition for using time series analysis is understanding of possible estimate process difficulties. If particular principles are broken, time series analysis produces erroneous regressions. Firstly, an explanation to the fundamentals of set of time series and cointegration, as they apply to the Phillips curve. Following that, we will examine the concept of the errors correction mechanism in order to comprehend its benefits in terms of a study of the Phillips curve.

The compliance of three Gauss-Makrov principles, specifically a steady anticipated value over time, an uniform variation over time, and a covariance of the solitary length of the lag k that is not time – dependent, is one prerequisite for a good conclusion. If the time series’ criteria are satisfied, it is said to be stationary, and a basic least – square approximation yields right output.

 

Once one or more of such conditions is violated, we have the challenge of regression analysis, which indicates that our estimation produces a connection that does not exist. Non-stationary activities are those that contravene the requirements of stationary phenomena.

A first comprehensive examination of the time – series data reveals that both inflation and unemployment are non-stationary phenomena, which raises the possibility of false regression.

Political Consequences

When employing the ADF test, the initial variance of both of such parameters is at minimum steady at the 5percentage significant level. As a result, both time series are merged in the first order I (1), allowing us to do a short evaluation. The AIC & BIC have been used to determine the ideal lag duration. Furthermore, an additional study employing the Engle-Granger approach showed that both parameters cointegrated CI (1, 1) at the 1 % level of significance, indicating a long term link. As previously said, this is the first evidence of a lack of the normal rate of unemployment. Despite the fact that both parameters are significantly positively correlated, this connection might vary with time.

The prediction of the long run connection resulted in an updated determination coefficient of 0.50 and an F-test indicating a 1 percent significance threshold for high approximation quality. Additionally, the study of the independent variable is encouraging, as the steady and unemployment are dissimilar from 0 at the 1.0% level of significance.

 

Theoretically, there is an inverse link involving unemployment and inflation. Opposite to natural rates unemployment concept, this leads in a long term link across both parameters. Since the approximation is a logarithmic of the parameters, a straightforward understanding of the factors is not feasible. When it is transformed back, it is typically considered that inflation is steady at 5.80 percent when there is no unemployment. In the instance of unemployment, such a change is unnecessary because we may easily read this as flexibility. When unemployment LUNP lowers by 1%, inflation increases by 0.40 %. Nevertheless, unlike the conceptual Phillips curve, this just represents the relationship between inflation rate and does not educate us about the effect of inflation on the rate of unemployment. To rule out correlations and assure the stability of the approximation, a dynamically approximation of the framework will be evaluated, which involves the lags of the differenced inflationary and the lag differences of the rate of unemployment, and a time series data parameter named.

Conclusion

The purpose of this study was to analyse the Phillips Curve hypothesis in the situation. During this period, had a fairly polarized political system, as well as a problem with chronically high inflation, especially in the 1980s and 1990s. According to their findings, rising inflation might be attributable to political parties’ unwillingness to commit to price stability in advance. Increasing inflation, on the other hand, may have resulted in greater job opportunities for a certain nation, which would have eventually led to economic development in the nation, which did not occur. This situation might have been caused by a number of causes, including high taxes, monetary policy instability, underinvestment, continued political bribery, and a lack of democratic initiative.

References

Andrés, J., Arce, Ó., & Burriel, P. (2021). Market polarization and the Phillips curve.  https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3781594

Ba?bura, M., & Bobeica, E. (2022). Does the Phillips curve help to forecast euro area inflation?. International Journal of Forecasting.

Berson, C., de Charsonville, L., Diev, P., Faubert, V., Ferrara, L., Guilloux-Nefussi, S., … & Mogliani, M. (2018). Does the Phillips curve still exist?. Rue de la Banque, (56).

Blanchard, O. (2016). The Phillips Curve: Back to the’60s?. American Economic Review, 106(5), 31-34.

Chowdhury, K. B., & Sarkar, N. (2017). Is the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve stable? Evidence from some emerging economies. Journal of Quantitative Economics, 15(3), 427- 449.

Davig, T. (2016). Phillips curve instability and optimal monetary policy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 48(1), 233-246.

Del Negro, M., Lenza, M., Primiceri, G. E., & Tambalotti, A. (2020). What’s up with the Phillips Curve? (No. w27003). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Gagnon, J., & Collins, C. G. (2019). Low inflation bends the Phillips curve. Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper, (19-6).

Leduc, S., & Wilson, D. J. (2017). Has the Wage Phillips Curve Gone Dormant?. FRBSF Economic Letter, 30, 16.

Lipsey, R. G. (2016). The Phillips curve and an assumed unique macroeconomic equilibrium in historical context. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 38(4), 415-429.

Salisu, A. A., Ademuyiwa, I., & Isah, K. O. (2018). Revisiting the forecasting accuracy of Phillips curve: the role of oil price. Energy Economics, 70, 334-356.

Tallman, E. W., & Zaman, S. (2017). Forecasting inflation: Phillips curve effects on services price measures. International Journal of Forecasting, 33(2), 442-457.