Quantitative Easing Policy And Its Effects On Key Economic Variables – A Case Study On Japan

Opinions in the approval of Quantitative Easing Policy

Quantitative Easing Policy simply refers to the alternative monetary plan in which central banks buys budgetary tools and financial possessions owned by commercial banks purposely to motivate the growth of an economy, and upsurge the monetary foundations. It emanates into application when the normal monetary policy proves to be unsuccessful, and the markets strive for an outside promoter to kindle the economy (Krishnamurthy and Vissing, 2011, p.114).

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

Opinions in the approval of Quantitative Easing Policy

In the event of economic downturn, governments incline to put on expansionary financial policy so as to depose the interest rates and encourage economic growth; however, when the of these interests approaches zero, this monetary policy turns almost useless. During these conditions, the central bank begins to purchase financial assets from the commercial banks and other monetary organizations leading to an inflow of money into the market (Krishnamurthy and Vissing, 2011, p.120).

The buying of these financial capitals by the central bank brands gives them more value which consecutively reduces their yield. As they turn out to be more costly to buy, both banks and financial organizations give inclination to utilizing the incoming money in supplying other possessions like stock and pledges over purchasing additional of these assets. This primes to a condition in which all the monetary bodies are ready to offer loans and invest in several other institutions leading to a considerable decline in the rates of interests. Consequently, an upsurge in the expenditure practices is noticed, leading to stabilization in the economy sector (Krishnamurthy and Vissing, 2011, p.126).

This task describes an exploration to gauge the effects as a result of enactment of this policy on the economic sector and specifically, bank loaning of the most noticeable preceding example of exceptional monetary incentive, the Japan’s “policy of quantitative easing” commonly referred to as QEP. In the outcome of the abounding of Japan’s fizz economy of the year 1990, trade and industry activities deteriorated and the consumer price depression become entrenched. The BOJ (Bank of Japan) despite reducing its policy rates to absolute zero level by the year 1999, the condition refused to reverse (Shiratsuka, 2011, p.187). In the year 2001, deterioration in consumer prices, weakening banking systems and the overlook of the repeated recession as a result of worldwide IT bubble collapse stimulated the Bank of Japan to introduce QEP (Bowman, Cai, Davies & Kamin, 2011, p.156).

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

The Quantitative Easing Policy comprised of 3 major key basics: (1) the Bank of Japan reformed its main objective of operation from uncollateralized dramatic call rates to due current account of balances (CABs) apprehended by monetary organizations at the Bank of Japan, and eventually advanced the CAB very well in surplus of the needed reserves. (2) The Bank of Japan advanced its securing levels of government pledges by incorporating long term JGBs with several other possessions purposely to realize the anticipated increase in CABs. (3) The Bank of Japan devoted to uphold the QEP up to when the core CPI stopped to decline (Bowman et al.,  2011, p.158).

Implementation of Quantitative Easing Policy in Japan

The Quantitative Easing Policy started in May 2001 having a targeted CAB of about 5 trillion, greater than the needed reserves of 4 trillion. The Bank of Japan with time upraised its anticipated range to 6-7 % of Gross Domestic Product by the start of the year 2004 and sustained it at that position for several years. This was absolutely well in extra of needed reserves and past the aggregate necessary to keep dramatic rates at the level of zero as depicted in the figure below.

During this duration of QEP, both the 3-month Treasury bill and the uncollateralized call proportion fell to approximately zero while the ratio of bank loans declined steadily. The Bank of Japan officially ended the Quantitative Easing Policy in March the year 2006 and returned to the instant call rates as its target policy. Though, it didn’t increase the call rate until July in order to permit the current account balances to be exhausted as shown in the figure below (Spiegel, 2014, p.87).

Most of the analysts do come into an agreement that the Quantitative Easing Policy was not that very effective in realizing its objective of encouraging amassed demand adequately to do away with the persistent deflation. (Shirakawa, 2012,p.129) .Ensuing the shallow financial crisis which took place between the years 2001 and 2002, Japanese Gross Domestic Product growth was put into a solid but dull position insufficient to lift the price rises from the negative zones as indicated below.

The argument that the Quantitative Easing Policy failed to realize its crucial objective of eradicating deflation, though, didn’t show that it delivered no spur to Japanese economy. It’s probable that the QEP put forth positive impacts, but simply overcome by the setback on the aggregate expenditure which resulted from the severe weaknesses in the area of banking and the balance sheet snags amid of both the households and the firms (Spiegel, 2014, p.87).

There are several ways by which the Quantitative Easing Policy motivated expenditure. To begin with, BOJ’s absolute purchases of JGBs contributed in lowering the long-term rates of interest, despite the fact that the existing investigation does not show its impacts, simply because the acquisitions were not adequate (Shirakawa, 2012, p.156). Secondly, by compelling to maintain the rates of interest low up to when the end of deflation period, QEP abridged the likely prospect interest rates and lowered the insignificant long-term proportions, while amassing the anticipated inflation and lowering the actual interest rates. These effects were though relatively small (Spiegel, 2014, p.87).

 Finally, QEP functioned through the credit channel of the economic policy to increase the liquidity of financial institutions so that they stretched their lending supply and making loans more accessible to bank-hooked on borrowers, good motive to rely on Japanese financial institutions may have wanted supplementary liquidity.

Shirakawa (2012) pointed out that while demand for extra reserves declined shortly after the year 2001 terrorist occurrence, in most established nations, demand remained considerably great in japan owing to apprehensions over commercial bankruptcies as well as the declining equity prices. Kimura et al (2013) likewise argued that enabling liquidity had a steadying effect on the monetary markets and possibly induced a portfolio move which led to credit extension.

Effects of Quantitative Easing Policy on Key Economic Variables in Japan

The Theory of QEP and Negative Interest Policy based on Japanese Experience.

Making use of a two- period overlapping generations’ model, this research revealed how the quantitative easing policy affects an economy based on the above scenario of Japanese economy. Since QEP forced a huge amount of money notice (Kurihara,2012,p.47) Consequently, the rate of return for money went up. This implied deflation acceleration in Japan, which was in line with the reality. On the other hand, QEP stimulated the aggregate demand which brought about a mild recovery in business. This business upturn tightened the foreign market by increasing the imports and caused the home currency to depreciate. (Fawley and Neely, 2012, p.154).

Negative Interest Policy depicts that there is tax imposed on money hoarding and as long as the government spending is maintained constant, money circulation obviously declines, thereby discouraging businesses. Such a recession reduces cumulative earnings and imports. This prompts excess supply of foreign exchange and consequently leading to appreciation of the exchange rate to bring the market into equilibrium. These characteristics of business cycle in reference to the changes in the monetary authority decisions became entirely consisted with the Japanese experience under the Abenomics. (Fawley and Neely, 2012, p.128).

The two- period overlapping generations’ model

Considering a two period overlapping-generations model of a production economy with vast time horizon, this economy under a supple exchange rate consumes two types of goods: goods, x, in which the economy major in; goods, y, which are manufactured in the rest of the world and circulated internationally. Assuming that one unit of labour produces one units of goods, x, and the opportunity to work which also means a chance to earn income is restricted within the young age bracket (Fawley and Neely, 2012, p.133).

There are two assets ensuing to no nominal interest: these assets are home and foreign currency. Goods in each economy are only available by its own currency. An assumption is made that no individual has inheritance motive and the balance of payments is always maintained at equilibrium. Precisely, the excess balance of payments denotes that the old generation of home economy bestows the foreign currency to their heirs because global loans between the same generations are infeasible by the harmonization of earning opportunity. (Fawley and Neely, 2012, p.154).

In the contrary case, when the balance of payments falls in debit the old generation turns out bankrupt and thus normal young individuals never sell their produced goods in advance. This model considers two sectors of the economy; individuals and Firms. ( Shirakawa, 2012,p.113)

The utility function U of citizens of this economy is similar 

Where is the composition of goods consumed by the i-th stage during period t   and are the consumption of home and foreign goods respectively. denotes the disutility of labour. is a definition function taking unity value when a person is employed and zero when a person is unemployed.u(.) is awell-behaved and homothetic value function. (Fawley and Neely, 2012, p.154).

An elementary calculation leads to the expenditure function

Analysis of the Effectiveness of Quantitative Easing Policy

Where represents the price of home goods during the period t, and  is that of foreign goods .t denotes nominal exchange rates. From the linear homogeneity of expenditure function, the 2nd equation can be changed into

Where et  represents the real exchange rate during the time t and is the inflation rate in terms of home goods. To abbreviate the adjustment process an assumption is made that home economy is stationary i.e.

The 3rd equation above can be rewritten as

Every firm is assumed to be a price taker and faces the linear homogenous production function on its own; profit becomes zero in the state of equilibrium. Therefore, the equation below is obtained (Wieland, 2011, p.123).

Where is the nominal reservation wage, as confirmed by the right hand of the above equation.

The above equation outlines the participation limitation for individuals. It implies that every time the home currency devalues disinflation advances. (Joyce et al, 2015). This is because such depreciation deprives the people responsible for expensive import goods; hence, the inflation rate in terms of the home goods should be calmed to cater for this disadvantage. As a result, foreign business cycle circulates through an adjoining variation in relation to trading activities.in this case, the employment segregation effect is unsatisfactory even though the balance of payments is always in equilibrium as (Fawley and Neely, 2012) emphasize in a more undeveloped model.

Based on the two period overlapping-generation model of a production economy, the following results were realized.

The radical QEP not only encourages an economy but also quickens deflation. This is because of a rapid monetary extension which requires a higher rate of return for a widely demarcated liquidity. Additionally, the higher income in relation to boom upsurges the import demand and In order to equilibrate the foreign currency market, the actual exchange rate depreciates. (Fawley and Neely, 2012, p.154).

The Taylor theory, zero inferior bound, and two stable states

As revealed by Joyce et al. (2015), two stable situations occur when the Taylor rule becomes non-linear as a result of the zero inferior bound on the rates of nominal interest: an inflationary stable state, and a deflationary stable state. The equations underneath reformulate this discussion, with the intertemporal financial plan limitations built just above.

 In the typical economic model, households are expected to utilize their possessions by the end of their life. That is

This is referred to as the transversally state in the literature. If households exploit their utility, this state must be fulfilled in equilibrium. Otherwise, households could upsurge their utility by spending their residual properties, which would controvert the designation of equilibrium (Fawley and Neely, 2012).

Substituting into the equation above we have  Which implies that the monetary authority repays all government bonds ultimately. It is also expected that households utilize their money by the end of their life. This implies that No exact forms are assumed for financial and monetary rules here. Any activity may be taken, as far as it satisfies the conditions above.

Due to the special interest on reserves, the central bank has two policy tools which it can aim at independently: the rate of nominal interest and the supply of foundation money. It is assumed that the central bank adopts the Taylor rule to decide the rate of nominal interest that is:

Theory of QEP and Negative Interest Policy based on Japanese Experience

Denote the actual rate of interest in the inflationary stable state by  being the rate of inflation in the inflationary stable state, which is the same as central bank’s aim rate of inflation. Making use of Fisher equation, the rate of nominal interest attained in the inflationary stable state is shown by. It’s consequently assumed that the central bank adopts the Taylor principle,  

In a small interest rate state, however, the rate of nominal interest is regularly subject to the zero subordinate bound. The equation above stops to be relevant as it is. Instead, it is rewritten as follows.

Evidently, the zero inferior bound on the rate of nominal interest presents non-linearity in the Taylor rule. This brings about a two stable states. In modern economics, households are presumed to create an ideal choice in consumption, financial possessions, etc., subject to their budget limitation, taking economic and monetary procedures as given. Then the market clearance conditions are enacted to resolve for an equilibrium pathway. Any particular model is not specified here, this is because the argument below is more or less appropriate to a broad variety of the economic models used.

 Supposing that an economy attains the inflationary stable state, then, the rate of inflation is given by  the rate of nominal interest by  and the actual interest rate by .This is what the central bank assumes to happen ultimately, when makes use of the Taylor rule

In addition to inflationary stable state, the other stable state is defined, i.e., the deflationary stable state as follows. Let  and  Then we have The rate of nominal interest hits the zero inferior bound. Thus, we have  from equation above. Since  by definition, we have, which implies deflation. This situation is referred to as deflationary stable state also called a liquidity trap. Note that the actual rate of interest in the deflationary stable state is similar to that seen in the inflationary stable state. As it is clear in the third equation, the actual interest rate defines relative prices between present and prospect consumption goods. As long as the actual interest rate is unaffected, households don’t change their course of actions, and therefore no differences in actual terms between the two stable states.

Nevertheless, the deflationary stable state is not equally desirable to the inflationary stable state. If external blows and nominal resistances could be ignored, it would not matter the stable state an economy was in. Households would relish the same amount of intake. However, it matters since external blows and nominal resistances can’t be ignored. Assuming that the economy is in inflationary stable state primarily, if it is hit by an external blow, the central bank regulates the rate of nominal interest instantly and the economy returns to its initial state as soon as possible.

The welfare decline will be considerably small in this scenario even with nominal resistances. Alternatively, supposing that the economy is under the deflationary stable state originally, as the zero inferior bound is mandatory, the central bank can’t lower the rates of nominal interest in reaction to adverse blows and thus fails to upsurge the economy back to the original state. The loss caused by nominal resistances will therefore be larger.

Empirical evidence from the Taylor Rule

The extend of the financial crisis in many nations means that Taylor rules recommends negative rates of nominal interest but rates of market interests are excellently bounded by zero (or almost to zero) because proxies can always hold non-interest bearing money. With the rates of interest that central banks can settle at or almost to zero, other rates of interest or forms of economic policies needs to be put into consideration(Fawley and Neely, 2012).

Conclusion

To sum up on the key findings of this research, a strong, optimistic and also statistically substantial impact of financial institution liquidity points on loaning is identified, this is a proposal that the extension of reserves linked with Quantitative Easing Policy most likely enhanced the course of credit to the budget (Kapetanios et al, 2011, p.114) .Nevertheless, for numerous reasons, the general extend of that increase was considerably very trivial. First, the valued figure on liquidity states in the board information deteriorations is quite very small.

Secondly, it is clear that much of these effects of the Bank of Japan’s reserve contribution on financial institution liquidity were counterweigh as financial organizations reduced their loaning abilities to each other making banks’ general liquidity escalate by less than their considerable current account of balances with the Bank of Japan. Lastly, the impacts of liquidity on loaning seems to have only maintained at the early years of Quantitative Easing Policy, when the banking sector was at its fragile state and thus Quantitative Easing Policy was most likely to have been helpful; by 2005, even before the Quantitative Easing Policy was out of control and the connection between liquidity and loaning to fade away.

Spiegel, 2014. How quantitative easing by the BOJ” work”?. FRBSF Economic Bronchure.

Ugai, H., 2011. impacts of the quantitative easing policy: A analysis of empirical survey. Monetary and  Economic 22(6), p.4.

Shirakawa, 2012. 1 year under” quantitative easing”. Institute for financial and Economic Studies, BOJ.

Shiratsuka, 2011. Magnitude and composition of the BOJ: Revisiting Japan’s Encounter of the QEP. Monetary and Economy Studies, 23(4), pp.71-105.

Joyce, Miles, Scott, and Vayanos, 2015. Quantitative easing and unusual financial policy–The Economic Journal, 123(589).

Wieland, 2011. Quantitative policy of easing: a rationale and some indication from Japan (No. w155656). National Bureau Research.

Krishnamurthy. and Vissing-Jorgensen, 2015. The effects of quantitative policy of easing on the rates of interest: channels and repercussions for policy (No. w17755). National Bureau Research.

Fawley,and Neely, 2013. 4 stories of quantitative easing. Federal Bank of St. Louis Review, 94(3), pp.52-81.

Joyce, Miles, Scott, and Vayanos, 2012. Quantitative and the unconventional financial policy–a beggining. The Economic Journal, 123(524).

Ugai, 2012. The Effects of the quantitative  policy: A survey and empirical analyses. Monetary Studies-Bank in Japan, 25(2), p.2.

Kapetanios, Mumtaz, Stevens, and Theodoridis, 2011. Assessing on the economy?broad effects of the quantitative easing. The Journal of Economics, 122(264).

Kurihara, 2012. The existing connection between rate of exchange and stock costs at the quantitative easing policy in Japan. The International Business journal, 11(4), p.375.

Bowman, Cai, Davies, and Kamin, S., 2012. The Quantitative theory of easing and bank lending: confirmation from Japan.